Murray N. Rothbard: In Memorium
Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute, 1995, pp. 13-18
Murray Rothbard (1926-1995)
Roger W. Garrison
In the late 1960s,
my interests were far removed from Austrian economics�and from any other
brand of economics, for that matter. I hadn't yet heard of Murray Rothbard
and thus couldn't even have imagined that I would be catapulted by him
into the midst of what would later be termed the "Austrian Revival." My
degree was in electrical engineering, but the hoped-for career was stillborn
because of Southeast Asia and the military draft. My years in uniform taught
me the importance of having a purpose by depriving me�temporarily�of the
possibility of having one. I did have time to read in the military, and
like many others in that period, I began reading Ayn Rand's novels as well
as her essays in moral philosophy.
Objectivism is strong medicine,
especially for those like myself who had spent their college years avoiding
courses in the social sciences because of their apparent lack of structure
and reason. Rand's Capitalism: the Unknown Ideal was full of structure
and reason and provided a moral foundation for a free society. The Austrian
economists, featured in this book's recommended readings, would show just
what is�or ought to be�sitting on Rand's foundation. Austrian economics
is appealing to an engineering mind: basic principles, law-like propositions,
unequivocal conclusions�all grounded in logic and applicable to the world
as we know it. Authors that Rand believed to be worthy of attention are
listed in alphabetical order. I look back now at my yellowed paperback
purchased more than a quarter-century ago and note the neatly drawn check
marks that track the progress of my reading: books by Benjamin Anderson,
Lawrence Fertig, Henry Hazlitt, and Ludwig von Mises. Although my imperfect
memory tells me that Murray Rothbard's books were included in this list,
I see now that they are not. But Rothbard had been publishing for several
years and was for a time a member of Rand's inner circle. Any enthusiastic
reader would soon find his books.
I obtained a copy of America's
Great Depression through an inter-library loan. I found Rothbard's
account of boom and bust absolutely compelling and especially significant
in light of the stark contrast between the views of the Austrian economists
and those of the "educated" citizenry. With a monopoly on money creation,
the government could artificially cheapen credit and orchestrate a business
expansion, which eventually and inevitably would collapse. Policies commonly
defended in the name of stability and growth led instead to instability
and decay. In later years, I would attach even more significance to this
early book of Rothbard's as I discovered how badly other schools of economic
thought had botched their accounts of business cycles.
With the engineering market
glutted in the early 1970s when I and many of my peers were set free by
the military, a popular option was to work on an MBA degree. I chose to
pursue a masters in economics instead, thinking (erroneously) that the
MA would be as marketable and the coursework more interesting. I entered
the masters program at the University of Missouri at Kansas City. The courses
on macroeconomics offered a steady diet of Keynesian analysis in the conventional
form of interlocking diagrams that jointly determine the equilibrium values
for the economy's income and its interest rate. The substantial investment
involved in mastering the diagrammatical technique seemed to give professors
and students alike a special interest in defending Keynesian views.
In late 1972 I began to
devise an Austrian counterpart to the Keynesian diagrams. Rothbard's Man,
Economy, and State provided the primary source material. In the end,
I was able to draw together individual diagrams taken from or inspired
by Rothbard, Mises, Hayek, Böhm-Bawerk and Wicksell and show that
they all fit together into a coherent story about boom and bust. Titled
"Austrian Macroeconomics: A Diagrammatical Exposition," the paper was submitted
as partial fulfillment of the course requirements in macroeconomics. The
professor, whose preferred brand of economics was institutionalism as exposited
by Thorstein Veblen and Clarence Ayers, gave me a high mark on the paper
but confessed that he hadn't actually worked through the graphical analysis
and wasn't familiar with Austrian economics. To my surprise, though, he
offered to arrange for me to present the paper at the Midwest Economic
Association meetings to be held in Chicago in April 1973.
With some urging from this
professor, I agreed to go to Chicago. I soon realized, however, that neither
he nor anyone else had provided me with any critical feedback. No one,
in fact, had actually read the paper. And I was to present it to a professional
audience in April! The one action item that occurred to me was to mail
a copy of the paper to Murray Rothbard. Maybe he would respond in time
to give me some confidence about Chicago�or to allow me to renege on my
agreement to go.
About a week after mailing
the paper, I got a phone call�from Joey Rothbard. She introduced herself
with a very pleasant voice and said that her husband would like to speak
with me. I then listened for the voice of a learned professor but heard
instead an exceedingly jolly voice, interspersed with an infectious cackling
and irreverent asides about modern-day graduate programs. Rothbard was
clearly enthused about the diagrammatical exposition; he saw it as beating
the Keynesians at their own game. "Would you be coming to New York anytime
soon?" he asked. Although I had no plans whatever to go to New York, I
managed to announce: "I'll be there during spring break," at which point
he invited me for dinner and further discussion of the diagrams.
Dinner guests at the Rothbards'
are made to feel like special people. I was treated to a memorable dinner
with the warmest hospitality amid the book-lined walls of the Rothbards'
upper-westside apartment. After dinner more guests arrived: Walter Block,
Walter Grinder, and William Stewart, all of whom had carefully read my
paper. The discussion was lively, mostly positive, and full of good suggestions
for revision and further development. I took notes in the margins of my
own copy. The evening passed quickly, and I began to worry about overstaying
my welcome. But no one else seemed to be aware of the late hour. As midnight
neared, I began packing my papers away and thanking the Rothbards for an
unforgettable evening. The host and other guests seemed puzzled and almost
insulted by my tenuous movement in the direction of the front door. I did
not know that Murray was a complete and incurable night owl. For him the
evening had just begun. We had lots of discussion ahead of us including
some history and some methodology and quite a little bit of slightly gossipy
banter about people in the Libertarian/Austrian movement. As best I can
remember, I was allowed to leave around 4:00 a.m., after an invitation
was extended (and accepted) to attend a class later in the day at Brooklyn
Polytechnic Institute, where Murray taught economics to engineering students�and
to stop by Laissez-Faire Books, where he would be autographing copies of
his just-released For a New Liberty (See photo). The evening had
crystallized into a major stepping stone in my own professional development.
But there was something else that had happened which now has a special
meaning for me. In the course of a single evening, Murray Rothbard, whose
name continued to signify eminence in economics, history, and philosophy,
had become for me just "Murray."
The presentation in Chicago was a virtual non-event, which, as I learned
later, is typical of sessions at professional meetings. But the disappointment
was overshadowed by the fact that Murray had invited me to attend a week-long
conference on twentieth-century American economic history sponsored by
the Institute for Humane Studies to be held in the summer at Cornell University.
He and Forrest McDonald were to lecture for a week to an audience consisting
mainly of student historians. As it turned out, I was one of only a few
economics students to attend. Near the end of the week, Murray asked me
to present my diagrammatics in an informal afternoon session. I foolishly
agreed. Since the audience of historians was largely unschooled in macroeconomics,
I felt I had to present first the mainstream Keynesian diagrammatics (which
typically takes a semester in undergraduate economics programs) and then
counter it with my own Austrian diagrammatics. Needless to say, the session
was a disaster. The audience, largely baffled, did include one economist,
who criticized me roundly at every turn. But I forgave Murray for asking
me to do the presentation and soon enough came to appreciate the criticisms
offered by the lone economist. She is to be thanked rather than forgiven.
Although the week at Cornell
was rewarding in its own right, it benefited me mainly by putting me on
the invitation list for upcoming conferences in Austrian economics. The
following year (1974) was the South Royalton conference, a conference that
came to be widely recognized as the take-off point of the Austrian Revival.
There, Murray, teamed up this time with Israel Kirzner and Ludwig Lachmann,
gave stimulating lectures dealing with method, theory, and policy, all
published later on as The Foundations of Modern Austrian Economics,
edited by Ed Dolan. Henry Hazlitt and Bill Hutt added much insight and
perspective to the discussions. Milton Friedman was there for the opening
banquet. His now-famous remark that "there is no Austrian economics�only
good economics and bad economics" had a certain�but unintended�galvanizing
effect on conference. The list of listeners, most meeting one another for
the first time, now reads like a Who's Who in Austrian economics: Armentano,
Block, Ebeling, High, Lavoie, Moss, O'Driscoll, Rizzo, Salerno, Shenoy,
Vaughn. One purpose of the conference was to persuade Lachmann that there
was sufficient interest in Austrian economics to justify his coming out
of semi-retirement and teaching at New York University. By week's end,
the interest was not in doubt, and Lachmann soon began teaching at NYU.
For the two follow-on conferences
held in successive years, F. A. Hayek joined the original South Royalton
faculty. In 1975 the Austrians met at the University of Hartford in Connecticut;
in 1976 they met in England in Windsor Castle. At both conferences, papers
by South Royalton participants were presented and discussed. The Windsor
Castle papers, among which was my newly revised "Diagrammitical Expostition,"
were eventually published as New Directions in Austrian Economics,
edited by Lou Spadaro. This unique three-year sequence of conferences on
Austrian economics, engineered largely by Murray, nicely overlapped my
years in the graduate program at the University of Virginia, a school I
had chosen on Murray's recommendation.
I can easily say that Murray's
influence on my career has been so significant that I simply do not know
where I would be today or what I would be doing had it not been for his
guidance. I knew Murray for the last twenty-two years of his life. I look
back now and realize that he was not as old when I first dined with him
and Joey as I am now. In stature, though, he seemed to me then like the
Old Master�having more to show for his early years than most of us will
have in the longest lifetime. Since then, of course, his influence, both
personal and through his writing, has grown enormously. We owe much to
Murray for the fact that the years since South Royalton have seen a steady
growth of Austrian economics in universities both in the U.S. and abroad.
Beginning in 1976 there have been teaching conferences almost every year�at
Newark, DE, Oakland, CA, Boulder, CO, Milwaukee, WI, Auburn, AL, Palo Alto,
CA, Claremont, CA�sponsored first by the Institute for Humane Studies and
then by the Ludwig von Mises Institute. This year, the conference, billed
as the Mises University, will be held in Auburn and promises to be a most
significant event. Dedicated to the memory of Murray Rothbard, it will
feature more than two dozen faculty members lecturing on a wide range of
topics in economics, history, and philosophy.
Can Austrian economics survive
without Murray? Yes, it can and will survive and grow. Although his passing
leaves us all with an enduring sense of loss, we can see his life as the
virtual personification of dedication and purpose. His legacy will provide
us with the wisdom and the spirit to press on.
|